Salt Starvation in
British India – Consequences of High Salt Taxation in the Bengal
Presidency, 1765 to 1878.
[
This academic article considers
salt deprivation in more detail than in The Great Hedge of India,
and has full citations. It is copyright, but may be reproduced for
non-commercial use providing the author is acknowledged]
by Roy Moxham
Little seems to have been
written by modern historians about the physiological consequences of
salt deprivation that might have resulted from the high Salt Tax in
British India. Occasionally, there are brief references to salt being “a
basic necessity of life” (Brown 1989, 236), but without amplification.
Writers on famine in British India seem generally to have ignored salt
intake as a nutritional factor. The indexes to Bhatia’s Famines in
India (Bhatia 1967), and Seavoy’s Famine in Peasant Societies
(Seavoy 1986), for example, have no references to salt. In recent years
there has been much publicity about the evils of excessive salt
consumption, and this may have caused some to suppose that salt was
unnecessary. Thus, Weber writes of Gandhi: “Generally, however, the
thrust of his medical arguments, which should be much applauded by those
stressing the link between salt and hypertension, was that a normal diet
provided the salt needed for the body without the addition of sea or
rock salt which in fact was toxic” (Weber 1997, 80). Probably the best
overview of the Salt Tax and the need for salt in India is in Denton’s
The Hunger for Salt but, understandably given the massive scope
of the book, this is restricted to a one-page summary and is mostly
concerned with the twentieth century (Denton 1984, 84-5).
Gandhi’s salt march has
tended to focus attention on to the Salt Tax in the twentieth century,
whereas the Salt Tax was much greater in the earlier period of British
rule – especially in the Bengal Presidency. Consequences could be
expected to have been greater, and thus easier to observe, when the tax
was higher. For this reason, this essay concentrates on the situation in
the Bengal Presidency from 1765 to 1878. It seeks to investigate the
level of salt taxation over that period and its effect on the retail
price of salt relative to wages; the physiological necessity for salt
and the peculiar nature of salt hunger; the minimum salt intake
necessary to maintain health and to recover from illness; actual salt
consumption; and the particular consequences of a high Salt Tax in times
of famine.
Salt Taxation and
Prices
Salt in Bengal had been
taxed relatively lightly prior to British rule, but then became very
heavily taxed (Parliamentary Papers 1856, 142-153; Ray 1929-30). Under
the Mughals, the retail price of salt varied considerably, according to
the degree of local monopoly and difficulty of supply, but was generally
cheaper, relative to wages, than it became under the British (Sarkar
1987, 66-9,95; Marshall 1976, 130-5). The Mughals had levied a tax on
salt as it passed up the River Ganges to the interior. This had been at
the rate of 2 ½ per cent on Muslim, and 5 per cent on Hindu traders. In
addition, local rulers had sometime imposed small tolls. In the early
years of East India Company rule, a small “tax” had been levied by
imposing transit duties and a high ground rent on some salt works.
Swingeing taxation of
salt developed from the establishment of the Exclusive Company by Clive
in 1765. This private company, owned by the East India Company’s senior
servants, was given a total monopoly on salt. All production by others
was declared illegal. This enabled the Exclusive Company to double the
wholesale price of salt to Rs 2.47 a maund. [In order to compare like
with like, prices have been converted, if necessary, into Company’s
rupees with decimal points or fractions, and weights into maunds of
approximately 82 lb (Maccauly 1816, 10-14).] In 1768 the Exclusive
Company was forced to relinquish its monopoly on salt, and free
manufacture resumed. The wholesale price fell to Rs 1.48, which included
a Rs 0.3 tax to the East India Company.
In 1780, Hastings brought
salt manufacture under government control again, under a complicated
system of farming. The wholesale price was fixed at Rs 2, of which Rs
1.1 to Rs 1.5 went to the government as a “tax.” The farmers used their
sub-monopoly to raise the price of salt excessively. In 1788, therefore,
a system of direct government auctions was started. This “entirely
failed to break down any sub-monopoly’ and ‘great fluctuations occurred
in the sale price” until the auction system was changed in 1836, but it
did have the effect of increasing the tax collected by the government to
Rs 3.25 a maund. It remained at around this extraordinary level until
1878, when it was slightly reduced - to Rs 2.9 in Lower Bengal, and Rs
2.5 elsewhere in the Bengal Presidency (Strachey and Strachey 1882,
225).
The retail price of salt
at the beginning of 1878 in Patna, Allahabad, and Lucknow was recorded
as Rs 5 a maund (Department of Finance and Commerce 1885, 220). It seems
probable that it was at about that level in the interior of the Bengal
Presidency, depending on transport costs, in 1794, when the wholesale
price averaged 3 ¼ rupees (Parliamentary Papers 1856, 146). In 1836,
John Crawfurd described “a wholesale price of five rupees per maund upon
the spot, and without reference to distribution over an immense tract of
country, often without roads or bridges, for the most part with
indifferent ones, and notoriously deficient in capital” (Parliamentary
Papers 1836, Appendix 76: 196). He also referred to the situation in
1823, when “in many parts of the country the price rose to 12 rupees a
maund for adulterated salt”.
In general, over those 90
years, wage inflation reduced the relative burden. In his account of
rural Bengal written in 1794, Colebrooke describes the basic
agricultural wage as ranging from half a rupee to one rupee a month. In
addition he estimates the benefit of being allowed to cultivate some of
the employer’s land as being worth, at the most, another seven rupees a
year (Colebrooke 1806, 97). This gives a maximum monthly wage of Rs 1.6,
and a minimum somewhere below Rs 1.1. By 1878, in the much enlarged
Bengal Presidency, wages had risen considerably [as had prices], but in
many areas, as recorded in Prices and wages in India, still only
averaged three to four rupees a month (Department of Finance and
Commerce 1885, 428-9). This is probably an over-estimate for, as Datta
has pointed out, the figures were often only collected in the towns or
nearby ( Datta 1914, 1: Appendix G, 244),and “Zemindars in Bengal…get
their work done much cheaper”(246).
During those years,
however, much effort had been expended in controlling the supply of
cheap illicit salt into the Presidency. Among other measures:
A customs line was
established, which stretched across the whole of India, which in
1869 extended from the Indus to the Mahanadi in Madras, a distance
of 2,300 miles; and it was guarded by nearly 12,000 men and petty
officers...it consisted principally of an immense impenetrable hedge
of thorny trees and bushes, supplemented by stone wall and ditches,
across which no human being or beast of burden or vehicle could pass
without being subject to detention or search.
(Strachey and Strachey
1882, 219-20)
By 1878, therefore, it
would have been much harder to obtain untaxed salt.
[By 1930, at the time of
Gandhi’s salt march, inflation had increased the monthly wage of a rural
labourer in Bombay Province to about Rs 13.5 (Lal 1989, 28) but the Salt
Tax had been reduced to Rs 1 ¼ a maund (Weber 1997, 84).]
The Need for Salt
In recent years there has
been much publicity about the need to reduce salt consumption in
societies where salt is added to many processed foods (Denton 1984,
584-7). [The health benefits of any general reduction in salt
consumption are still being assessed, and contentious (Alderman, Cohen,
and Madhavan 1998, 781-5).] It has tended to be forgotten that some salt
intake is absolutely necessary; that people need salt, sodium chloride,
to survive:
The chemical
requirements of the human body demand that the salt concentration in
the blood be kept constant. If the body does not get enough salt, a
hormonal mechanism compensates by reducing the excretion of salt in
the urine and sweat. But it cannot reduce this output to zero. On a
completely salt-free diet the body steadily loses small amounts of
salt via the kidneys and sweat glands. It then attempts to adjust
this by accelerating its secretion of water, so that the blood’s
salt concentration can be maintained at the vital level. The result
is a gradual desiccation of the body and finally death.
(Bloch 1963, 89)
Salt normally comprises
about 1/400 of body weight (Marriott 1950, 6). In a 150-lb man this
would be six ounces. In hot environments, especially when doing manual
labour, people sweat heavily and lose considerable quantities of salt
(35). In tropical countries “salt deficiency is perhaps the commonest of
all deficiency states” (22).
The desire for salt is
presumably in-built to ensure survival (Denton 1984, 604). Salt, up to a
certain limit, is pleasurable to eat. Where it is plentiful, people eat
more than they need – and if the body’s mechanism for secreting it is
impaired, more than is desirable. Unlike hunger or thirst, however, the
desire for salt does not increase when reserves are low (Marriott 1950,
22; Dill 1938, 82). For this reason people receiving too little salt
will find food bland, but often not realise why they are feeling
listless, or worse. Similarly, those whose salt reserves have been
depleted by illness will experience no added desire to consume salt.
Even doctors sometimes fail to recognise that patients are suffering
from salt depletion. As Dr Marriott has written in Water and Salt
Depletion: “their deaths are ascribed to ‘toxaemia’ or ‘uraemia’ or
‘circulatory failure’ when they have, in fact, died from simple lack of
salt and could easily have been saved” (Marriott 1950, 3-5). Since he
was writing of the situation in western hospitals in the middle of the
twentieth century, it can be appreciated that deaths caused by salt
depletion in eighteenth and nineteenth century Bengal would have been
even less likely to be correctly attributed.
Illness is a major cause
of salt depletion (Black 1953, 305-11). People who are already low on
salt are particularly vulnerable. Large quantities of salt can be lost
in fever-sweat, in vomit, and most of all in diarrhoea (Marriott 1950,
32-4). This should be continually replenished. Severe diarrhoeas can
drain as much as 1 ¾ ounces of salt from the body in a single day, and
thus quickly lead to severe dehydration. Without intravenous infusion of
saline solution – not an option in the period being considered –
recovery would have been unlikely (Souhami and Moxham 1990, 849).
However, milder diarrhoeas, which as any traveller can relate are common
in India, can over a few days also lead to severe depletion (Marriott
1950, 33). Rehydration can only be effected with the intake of salt.
Without this salt, however much water is drunk, recovery is impossible.
Many diarrhoeas are self limiting – that is they terminate of their own
accord, without drugs, after a few days. Rotavirus diarrhoea, which “is
the commonest cause of diarrhoea in children up to 2 years old in the
tropics” (Souhami and Moxham, 257), is an important example. It is
essential to keep the body from dehydrating, and salt is necessary for
this. The main ingredient of modern oral rehydration solutions is salt
(257).
Mild salt depletion,
resulting from insufficient salt in the diet, produces “extreme
lassitude” (Marriott 1950, 40). This will, of course, reduce economic
output. For people already on the edge of starvation, insufficient salt
will set up a cycle of economic decline.
*
Very small amounts of
sodium may be present in unprocessed foodstuffs. These have been
quantified by McCance (McCance 1936b, 647) together with the comment:
“You will notice how little some of them contain, and appreciate that
additional salt may be an absolute necessity when I tell you that I
would have to eat more than twice my own weight of potatoes every day to
get my physiological intake of sodium”. Meat contains more salt, but on
the basis of McCance’s figures a minimum of 8 ¼ lb would have to be
eaten daily. Many Indians were, of course, vegetarian. Even those that
were not would have gained little from what quantity of meat they did
eat, unless they were eating wild game, since domestic herbivores
require salt in their feed (Denton 1984, 54). Coastal dwellers may have
received some of their requirement from fish, and it can be assumed that
although manufacture of salt from seawater was illegal they took
advantage of the salt water for cooking.
Minimum Salt
Requirement
Exactly how much salt the
inhabitants of the Bengal Presidency required to maintain health is
difficult to estimate. Need would have depended on such variables as
body weight, metabolism, the work environment, and local climate. Some
people sweat more than others, and some have a higher concentration of
salt in their sweat (Ladell, Waterlow, and Hudson 1944, 491-7, 527-531).
Different researchers have come up with different minimum salt
requirements (Robinson 1949, 218-31). Under constant conditions, some
people seem able to reduce the loss of salt in their sweat to very low
levels (Conn 1949, 373-93; Dahl 1958, 1152-7). Acclimatisation may
reduce salt need (Collins 1963, 716-20). Some indigenous people in areas
where salt has been scarce historically, seem to have a very low salt
requirement (Denton 1984, 43-4). In contrast, for many others, living or
working in hot environments, high levels of salt consumption seem to be
essential (Ladell 1944, 492; McCance 1936a, 245-268; Haldane 1929, 469;
Dill 1938, 83-4). As Knut Schmidt-Nielsen has pointed out, “sweat
contains a variable amount of sodium chloride, but always enough to
cause a considerable salt loss when sweat is produced in quantities. A
relatively high intake of sodium chloride is therefore necessary”
(Schmidt-Nielsen 1964, 21). It is difficult, he also observes, to
collect sweat and other samples without altering the body’s environment,
and impossible to give general rules for cutaneous salt loss, “but we
can assume that, at high sweating rates, the total loss may easily run
to 10 to 30 grammes [0.35 to 1.06 oz] of sodium chloride a day” (5-8).
During the Second World
War a number of investigations into the heat exhaustion of both British
and Indian military personnel were conducted. It so happened that Dr
Marriott, a consultant physician at the Middlesex Hospital in London,
was posted inside the former Bengal Presidency:
It was my duty in
India to do special tours in the hottest weather (June) to observe
heat effects in such particularly hot stations as Allahabad,
Cawnpore, Lucknow, and Bareilly. The tour of 1942 was particularly
instructive, because it happened to be an unusually hot season
(maximum shade temperature in the above stations were between 115°
and 123° F. (46° and 50.6° C.)
and because in that year – the first real war year for India – there
was not adequate shade provision for men, nor was there general
realisation of the importance of extra salt intake. During this hot
season there were 1,959 admissions to hospital for heat effects and
136 deaths. I personally saw 400 cases.
(Marriott 1950, 35)
Similar salt depletion
was reported among troops with heat exhaustion in Iraq (Ladell,
Waterlow, and Hudson 1944). The daily hot station salt allowance was 21
grams, with another 10 grams estimated to be present in processed food,
making a total of 31 grams, or 1.09 oz. Many other troops, it should be
noted, found this intake adequate. In Iraq, a group of fit acclimatised
men were subject to extensive tests in hot conditions. The average loss
of salt in their sweat was calculated as 17.6 grams a day. There was
also a loss of at least 3 grams a day in the urine, giving a total daily
loss of 20.6 grams, or 0.73 oz.
Since salt hunger is not
related to requirement, it is impossible to adjust consumption to
exactly meet loss in sweat and urine. There must always be a surplus
available to cover possible need. Moreover, since without sophisticated
medical examination it is impossible to tell which people have the more
efficient salt metabolism, salt availability needs to be targeted at the
level of those with the higher need.
In the Bengal Presidency
less salt was necessary during the cool season. However, because of the
nature of salt hunger, it is unlikely that consumption would have fully
reflected this. Since the body cannot store excess salt for more than a
few days (Dill 1938, 81-2), unnecessary salt eaten in cooler weather
would have inevitably been excreted and thus wasted. Taking the figures
given above as a basis for necessary intake in hot weather, it seems
reasonable to assume a minimum average daily requirement over a year of
at least half an ounce of salt. This is equivalent to 11.4 lb a year.
Taking this figure of
11.4 lb for an adult, the requirement for a family can be calculated. If
it is assumed that an average family contained two adults and three
children, with the children consuming half that of the adults, then a
family requirement of 39.9 lb of salt a year results. This amount makes
no provision for any wastage or illness. [ It also makes no provision
for the salt needed by cattle and other domestic livestock, which needed
salt just as humans did. Salt deprivation reduces milk yields (Denton
1984, 44). The economic and nutritional effect of restricting the salt
intake of cattle needs further research, as does the effect on cottage
industries that used salt, such as tanning and textile dying. ] 39.9 lb
of salt is just under half a maund, which is a convenient measure to use
in calculating cost.
Actual Salt Consumption
How much salt was
actually consumed? As has already been seen, the price of salt was often
about Rs 5 a maund [and sometimes much higher]. The minimum family
requirement of half a maund would have cost Rs 2 ½ . In 1788 this would
have represented about two months’ income for an agricultural labourer,
and by 1878 a month’s or more. It is clear that with such high level of
tax, the temptation would have been to economise on consumption.
Dr John Crawfurd,
formerly of the Bengal Medical Service, in his evidence before the 1836
Parliamentary Select Committee on salt in British India, disputed the
Salt Board’s assertion that nearly 12 lb of salt per head was supplied
to the population. He produced figures that gave a consumption of no
more than 7.69 lb a head. With regard to consumption being curtailed
because of the cost he said:
The Board of Customs
however, will have it, that under no possible circumstances is it
likely that a larger quantity of salt than 12 lb would be consumed
by the people of Bengal. They insist that, ‘the argument which holds
good of the superior productiveness of low prices on all articles in
general demand in civilised countries at home, is almost wholly
inapplicable to the salt trade in India, where the poorest
individual gets what custom and convenience have taught him to eat,
and where, such are the simple habits of the bulk of the society,
little more would be used, whatever were the extent of the supply
and then cheapness of the article.’ My own opinion is, that a more
unfounded opinion than this could not well be propounded. The people
of Bengal, I have no doubt, should they ever get cheap salt, will
consume it as largely as any other class of men.
(Parliamentary Papers 1836,
188)
Dr R. Moore, formerly
medical officer in charge of Midnapore District, was similarly examined
before the Select Committee of 1853:
Chairman: With regard
to the salt revenue, have you any observations to make upon that
subject?
Dr Moore: In the
first place the poorer people cannot get salt. Many people have
supposed that diseases arise in consequence of the deficiency.
(Parliamentary Papers 1853,
61)
Furthermore, salt was
often adulterated, as an 1852 petition from Calcutta testified:
Many proofs that the
duty presses with very great severity might be given, but one must
here be sufficient, namely, that out of Calcutta, as far as the
North-west Provinces, pure salt, as sold by the Government or
imported, is almost unknown to the mass of the people; adulterations
of all kinds are resorted to reduce its price to their means of
purchasing; a wholesome condiment is thus often rendered
unwholesome, and to all purposes for which pure salt is necessary
the duty is a prohibition.
(Parliamentary Papers 1856,
Appendix 7, 489)
Further compelling
evidence comes from an official source, the Commissioner’s 1868-69
Report on the Administration of the Inland Customs Department:
114. VII That,
excluding the salt-sources and their immediate vicinity, the
average consumption of adults in the belt of country extending
for 100 miles outside our cordon, where untaxed salt is available,
is certainly not less than 13 lb per adult and probably materially
exceeds this amount.
114. VIII That, both
by actual enquiry and by reference to population and supplies, it is
proved that the average consumed by adults within Line cannot exceed
8 lbs.
(Inland Customs Department
1869)
If the average was 8 lb,
many must have consumed less.
Abhay Charan Das in
The Indian Ryot, printed in 1881, wrote:
Then again there is a
still more wretched creature, who bears the name of labourer, whose
income may be fixed at thirty-five rupees per annum. If he, with his
wife and three children, consumes twenty-four seers [ 49 lb ] of
salt, he must pay a salt duty of two rupees and seven annas, or in
other words 7 ½ per cent income tax. Now we leave it to our readers
to judge, whether the ryots and the labourers can procure salt in
the quantities they require. We can positively state from our own
experience, that an ordinary ryot can never procure more than
two-thirds of what he requires, and that a labourer not more than
half.
(Das 1881, 363-4)
From the above
testimonies, it seems clear that salt consumption was severely reduced
by the high level of Salt Tax, and at times was perhaps not sufficient
to restore even the losses in sweat. This would have led to “a mild
breathlessness at first and sense of fatigue” (McCance 1936a, 251), with
consequent loss of economic output and resistance to disease. For the
very poor, extremely low salt levels would possibly have resulted in
“cramps, weakness, lassitude, and severe cardio-respiratory distress on
exertion” (267). They would have been particularly at risk from
salt-depleting illnesses, such as sweat-inducing fevers, and especially
from diarrhoeas. Whatever the minimal salt requirement of the healthy,
those with fevers and diarrhoeas would have been adversely affected by
any restriction on salt intake needed to replace losses.
Salt and Famine
In times of famine there
was no money to buy anything except basic food. As W.W. Hunter,
Director-General of Statistics to the Government of India, wrote in 1874
of lower Bengal, where wages were higher than in the northwest:
A household of four
persons, say two adults and two children, reduced to one meal a day,
consume 1 ½ seers of rice. In order to enable the father to do his
daily work, he would require a second meal of half a seer, making 2
seers a day. If the daily consumption dropped below this, severe
suffering would have to be endured. Now, at even the point that I
take to be the beginning of the famine, namely, Rs 4 a maund, or 10
seers to the rupee, this lower scale of diet would cost Rs 6 a
month. When rates rise to 8 seers for the rupee, or Rs 5 per maund,
2 seers a day would cost Rs 7 – 8 [Rs 7 ½] a month. Yet about a
fourth of the families in Bengal do not earn more than Rs 5 a month
even in prosperous times.
(Hunter 1874, 21-2)
In such circumstances,
there would have been no spare money to buy salt.
The Inland Customs
Commissioner’s report for 1877-78 records that 10,918 people were
arrested, of whom 2600 paid fines averaging Rs 6.52, and 3252 went to
prison in default (Inland Customs Department 1878, para 28). [These
figures only cover the jurisdiction within the vicinity of the Customs
Line, and there would have been other arrests for salt offences in other
areas of the Bengal Presidency.] This was a large increase on the
previous year. The Commissioner wrote: “This is owing to the distress
arising from the high price of grain having caused some persons to
resort to irregular means of livelihood; scarcity and distress causing
the Customs Laws to be made frequently offended against in common with
the other laws of the land”.
The “high price of grain”
is a reference to the famine that had devastated the North-Western
Provinces and Oudh. The official figure for famine induced deaths in the
14 months from November 1877 to December 1878 was 1,266,420
(Parliamentary Papers 1881, 203). Later enquiries and research has
concluded that this was a considerable under-estimate (Parliamentary
Papers 1881, 243-50; Arup). The most detailed investigation into actual
cause of death seems to have been by a Mr Roberts, who visited 62
villages in the districts of Agra, Etah, and Mainpuri. His figures
(Parliamentary Papers 1881, 245) give totals:
Hunger |
278 |
Bowel-complaints |
285 |
Small-pox |
310 |
Fever |
1184 |
Other causes |
240 |
Total |
2297 |
Thus, he concluded that
more people died of bowel complaints than of hunger.
The official “Statement
shewing the number of deaths (by different causes) in the North-Western
Provinces and Oudh” lists 165,334 deaths from “bowel complaints”
excluding cholera, sharply up from 84,615 the previous year
(Parliamentary Papers 1881, 232).
As has been seen,
diarrhoea leads to a severe drainage of salt. The body cannot be
rehydrated without consuming an equal quantity of salt. There was no
remission of the Salt Tax despite the famine. The nature of salt hunger
leads to it being given a lower priority than food hunger. Taking all
these factors into account, it seems likely that many would have died
from lack of salt. A similar situation would have occurred in the many
other famines that ravaged the Bengal Presidency between 1765 and 1879
(Parliamentary Papers 1881, 1-264).
Conclusion
Absolute proof as to what
occurred is unlikely to be forthcoming, and degrees of probability will
have to suffice. It seems clear that those who were unable to obtain any
salt at all would have died. How many were so poor as to die would have
varied from year to year, but in time of famine they would probably have
been numerous. Many more would have had their general health and
resistance to disease affected by too low a consumption of salt. Some of
these would have died from the secondary effects of reduced economic
output or susceptibility to disease, or a combination of the two. It
also seems clear that many of those with diarrhoeas, even though able to
obtain enough salt for normal use, would have perished. Some would have
died anyway, but it seems probable that the high Salt Tax would have
considerably increased their number.
It will be difficult, if
not impossible, to exactly quantify the damage to heath caused by salt
starvation. As has been seen, the symptoms of salt depletion were at the
time usually unrecognisable, and would have been ascribed to other
causes. Autopsy is presumably not an option, especially as most people
were probably cremated. Moreover, there are probably too many variables
to allow the use of the mortality and illness statistics from areas of
India that had cheaper salt to draw accurate comparisons. Nevertheless,
it is important to know whether the impact on health of the Salt Tax was
relatively small or very significant. Using modern medical, statistical
and historical knowledge, it may be possible to form a better picture of
events; to assess the broad magnitude of any damage to health, and
roughly quantify excess mortality. Experiences in modern famines could
perhaps assist interpretation; there may be useful parallels in other
countries. A fuller analysis will only become possible with
contributions from experts in many different fields, and I hope this
essay will encourage that process.
List of References
ALDERMAN, MICHAEL H.,
COHEN, HILLEL, and MADHAVAN, SHANTHA. 1998. “Dietary sodium intake and
mortality: the National Health and Nutrition Examination Survey (NHANES
I).” The Lancet 351: 781-5.
ARUP, MAHARATNA. 1996.
The Demography of Famines: An Indian Historical Perspective. Delhi:
Oxford University Press.
BHATIA, BALMOKAND M.
1967. Famines in India: A Study in Some Aspects of the Economic
History of India (1860-1965), second edition. London: Asia
Publishing House.
BLACK, D. A. K. 1953.
“Body-Fluid Depletion.” The Lancet 1: 305-311.
BLOCH, M. R. 1963. “The
Social Influence of Salt.” Scientific American 209: 89 - 98.
BROWN, JUDITH MARGARET.
1989. Gandhi: Prisoner of Hope. New Haven: Yale University Press.
COLEBROOKE, HENRY THOMAS.
1806. Remarks on the Husbandry and Internal Commerce of Bengal.
Calcutta.
COLLINS, K. J. 1963.
“Endocrine Control of Salt and Water in Hot Conditions.” Federation
Proceedings 22: 716-20.
CONN, JEROME W. 1949.
“The Mechanism of Acclimatization to Heat.” Advances in Internal
Medicine III: 373-393.
DAHL, LEWIS K. 1958.
“Salt Intake and Salt Need.” New England Journal of Medicine 258:
1152-7.
DAS, ABHAY CHARAN. 1881.
The Indian Ryot, Land Tax, Permanent Settlement, and the Famine.
Howrah: Howrah Press.
DATTA, K. L. 1914.
Report on the Enquiry into the Rise of Prices in India. Calcutta:
Superintendent Government Printing.
DENTON, DEREK. 1984.
The Hunger for Salt: An Anthropological, Physiological and Medical
Analysis. Berlin: Springer – Verlag.
Department of Finance and
Commmerce, Statistical Branch. 1885. Prices and wages in India.
Calcutta: Superintendent of Government Printing.
DILL, DAVID BRUCE. 1938.
Life, Heat and Altitude: Physiological Effects of Hot Climates and
Great Heights. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
HALDANE, JOHN SCOTT.
1929. “Salt Depletion by Sweating.” British Medical Journal 2:
469.
HUNTER WILLIAM WILSON.
1874. Famine aspects of Bengal districts. London: Trubner.
Inland Customs
Department. 1869. Report on the administration of the Inland Customs
Department, 1868-69. Allahabad: Government Press.
___. 1878. Report on
the administration of the Inland Customs Department, 1877-78.
Allahabad: Government Press.
LADELL, W. S. S.,
WATERLOW, J. C. and HUDSON, M FAULKNER. 1944. “Desert Climate;
Physiological and Clinical Observations.” The Lancet 2: 491-7,
527-531.
LAL, DEEPAK. 1989. The
Hindu Equilibrium, 2: Aspects of Indian labour. Oxford: Clarendon.
MACCAULY, THOMAS. 1816.
The Indian Trader’s Complete Guide. Calcutta.
MARRIOTT, HUGH. LESLIE.
1950. Water and Salt Depletion. Springfield: Thomas.
MARSHALL, PETER J. 1976.
East India Fortunes: The British in Bengal in the Eighteenth Century.
Oxford: Clarendon.
McCANCE, R. A. 1936a.
“Experimental Sodium Chloride Deficiency in Man.” Proceedings Royal
Society B 119: 245-268.
___. 1936b. “Medical
Problems in Mineral Metabolism.” The Lancet: 230: 643 – 650.
Parliamentary Papers.
1836. “Report from the Select Committee on Salt, British India.” 518
XVII.
___.1853. "Fourth Report
from the Select Committee on Indian Territories, Minutes of Evidence."
692.
___. 1856. “Report of the
Commissioner appointed to inquire into and report upon the manufacture
and sale of salt in British India.” 2084 I XXVI.
___. 1881. “Report of the
Indian Famine Commission, Part III, Famine Histories.” C 3086 LXXI –
Part I.
RAY, PARIMAL. 1929 – 30.
“History of Taxation of Salt under the Rule of the East India Company.”
Calcutta Review, Series 3, 33: 175-194; 34: 35-43, 215-224,
347-354; 35: 17-21, 193-200, 321-325; 36: 29-34, 184-187, 340-344; 37:
64-67, 265-279.
ROBINSON, S. 1949.
“Physiological Adjustments to Heat.” In Physiology of Heat Regulation
and the Science of Clothing, edited by L. H. Newburgh, 1968
facsimile of 1949 edition. New York: Hafner.
SARKAR, JAGADISH NARAYAN.
1987. Mughal Economy: Organization and Working. Calcutta: Naya
Prokash.
SCHMIDT-NIELSEN, KNUT.
1964. Desert Animals: Physiological Problems of Heat and Water.
Oxford: Clarendon.
SEAVOY, RONALD E. 1986.
Famine in peasant societies. New York; London: Greenwood.
SOUHAMI, ROBERT L. and
MOXHAM, JOHN. 1990. Textbook of Medicine. Edinburgh: Churchill
Livingstone.
STRACHEY, JOHN and
STRACHEY, RICHARD. 1882. The Finances and Public Works of India from
1869 to 1881. London: Kegan Paul, Trench.
WEBER, THOMAS. 1997.
On the Salt March: The Historiography of Gandhi’s March to Dandi.
New Delhi: HarperCollins.
Copyright Roy Moxham 2000.