SALT MONOPOLIES -
CHINA
" The foreigner coming to China
earlier in this century would be struck by the care with which salt was treated in the
countryside. Salt was a government monopoly, heavily taxed and therefore
expensive." T.R.Tregear.
First mention of salt in China is found in
the annals of the Emperor Yu, BC 2205-2197 , who ordered the province of Shantung to
supply the court with that commodity During the Chow dynasty the administration of the
salt industry was conducted by court officials but the Crown monopoly of salt was not
instituted until the days of Kuan Chun who died in BC 645. Between AD 561 and AD583
references to various taxes on salt lead us to the conclusion that salt was produced at
that period from sea water salt marshes and salt springs and at the present day salt is
produced in China in three varieties sea-salt, lake salt, and well salt .
A government monopoly in China stretches
back over a period of about 2,500 years. Not only was salt production more sophisticated
at an earlier age than in other parts of the world but the monopoly was often more
effective. The country's needs and dependence on salt varied considerably at different
times. When Emperors and the authorities were strong and able to expand their control over
the provincesthe salt monopoly was both the means of establishing political power and also
financing their hegemony.
|
|
MONOPOLIES 3 - CHINA
THE SALT
SOURCES
Saltmaking is a very ancient industry. More than 4,000 years ago the
Chinese were boiling down brine in small pans from saline soil in desert basins and
relatively dry areas where the rainfall is not sufficient to wash the salts away. Salt
pools and patches of alkaline earth around the Great Bend of the Huang Ho - Yellow River -
are the most important in the north west: the most extensive and productive - 75% of the
total output - lie in Kiangsu Province and along the full length of the coastal strip.
Qinghai lake China's largest salt lake at 4580 sq/km, is today again to be developed
[together with another ancient salt producer [today the "Dead Sea WorksLtd] into a
rich resource for salts including potash, Qinghai province has another 27 salt lakes
located inthe "Caidam basin" known since ancient times as "The Treasure
Bowl"
Szechuan province in the south west exploited its salt-well technology
before the Christian era including blast furnaces to smelt iron and steel bits able to
bore holes up to a depth of 2,000 feet. Brine, brought up by bamboo tubes with leather
valves pushing and sucking was carried away to be boiled in large iron pans using natural
gas for fuel. About the same time, the Egyptians transported their brine in wooden pipes,
a technique only attempted in Europe during the 17th century. The Chinese could use
bamboo, hollowed out and joined together to provide an algae free, rot resistant piping.
Evaporation pans at various
stages of brine concentration - the brine flowing from the drill holes "welling"
up into the ponds, and finally heaped mounds of salt dry and ready for collection
AN EARLY STATE SALT
MONOPOLY
Between 685 and 643 BC. Ch'i state - modern
Shantung - rose to power mainly through 'an advantageous' trade in fish and salt. Its salt
pans were 'treasures of the state' - nationalised - and seem to have been the chief source
of natural wealth around 520 BC. Salt pans and forges were the principal industries its
factories turning out agricultural tools such as hoes and ploughs and, because war was
endemic, weapons for the army, the rebels and smugglers all struggling for power. After a
period of ruinous inter-state warring and social upheaval China became 'unified' first
under the Ch'in dynasty and then under the Han Emperors from 202BC. to 220 AD. with a
centralised monarchy and a loose federation of overlordships in the 'One Empire under
Heaven.' A new social structure allowed peasants to own land and an economy which used money began to evolve from
one based on
Drilling rig
circa 300AD The same rigs drilling for salt in Texas nearly 1800
years later were instrumental in finding crude oil.
agricultural products.
After grain, salt and iron were the two most important necessities in the ancient Chinese
empire at this time. But by 120 BC the Treasury was exhausted.
Taxes had risen, there was widespread illegal
minting of money and grain shortages had forced up prices. In some parts of the country
even salt became too expensive to buy. During the same year an attempt was made to reduce
inflation and to curb the 'nimble traders and unscrupulous merchants' by setting up a salt
and iron monopoly to cover a far great area than the Ch'i government had so successfully
done. Hsien Yang, a notable salt boiler and K'un Ch'in, a prosperous ironmaster were
appointed assistants to the Minister of Agriculture. Although salt and iron were
traditionally the responsibility of officials drawn from aristocratic families who often
held other powerful government position concurrently - this particular minister was also
head of Commerce and Finance departments - it was a deliberate policy of selection by
merit rather than birth that led to their appointment. Offices and stores were opened
between 117 and 115 BC. in an effort to 'equalize prices' by regulating the transport,
storage and distribution.
Salt officials also
competed with the merchants in the markets to buy cheaply when prices were low and resell
at reasonable cost from government depots in times of scarcity. The new appointees, Yung
and K'un travelled all over the Empire by post chaise of the '3rd category' - the price of
a ticket - to
China; Artificially boiling
brine
inaugurate the service and
to recruit experienced tradespeople, often the former owners, 'already enriched' to run
it. From 120 to 90 BC. rich industrialists and wealthy merchants built up prosperous
monopolies on natural 'resources from the mountains and marshes' on coinage, salt and
iron, steadily improving the revenue until around 100 BC. it was 'twenty times better.
DISCOURSES ON SALT
AND IRON
But the discontent which followed these changes was reflected in a
debate 'Discourses on Salt and Iron': the State Control of Commerce and Industry. The
controversy, begun in 81 BC between the government School of Law, the political and
philosophical wing of the former Ch'in dynasty, and the 'Litereati' traditionalists and
followers of Confucius, it covered domestic issues, economic questions and above all, the
ethics and philosophy of the time. The Legalists supported the nationalization of salt,
iron and grain to prevent competitive greed and corruption among the merchants and to
provide the steady, profitable revenue needed for national defence. As realistic statesmen
in power they had to satisfy the Emperor and Court as well as balance the budget. The
Literati appealed for the abolition of the salt and iron monopoly. Out of power and
wanting to regain the Emperor's confidence, they had nostalgic leanings towards feudalism,
deploring the unsettled state of the peasant farmers now liable for the new higher taxes.
The ancients, they argued, had managed the land so that it was sufficient for people's
needs ...'each was satisfied with his dwelling, customs, food and implements..' State
interference in the markets would mean officials competing with private traders and the
concentration of wealth in the government's hand might
Pipeline of hollow trees and
bamboo
'discourage individual initiative . Furthermore, they were critical of diversified responsibility.
'..No man in ancient times pursued two occupations at the same time...' In spite of the
financial success of the Salt and Iron monopoly the political climate was changing and by
45 BC. the Confucian scholars were 'in almost complete control at the Han Court. The
monopoly was abolished in 44 BC. but restored four years later during another crisis: and
the pioneer commissioners continued their professional careers in the Ministry of
Agriculture, K'un as Minister with Hsien as his assistant.
REORGANIZATION AND
PROVINCIAL AUTONOMY
Four dynasties later the Empire was again in disarray. Central
government in the provinces had broken down partly through over-stretching the resourses
in attempting to conquer new territories. A bitter civil war - An Lu Shan's rebellion in
755 AD. devastated the north causing serious economic and social disruption. Under the
T'ang Emperors 618 - 90 AD. the country was again unified and urgent fiscal reforms begun.
The emphasis was again on indirect taxation of commodities, the most important one being
the reintroduction of the Salt and Iron monopoly. 'Iron' was retained in the title out of
respect for the former Han Emperors; it was the salt which made the money. Again, two
able,energetic administrators took charge. Ti'wu Ch'i first, and then Liu Yen, created a
system of directorates and commissioners to control the saltmakers, buy up their output
and sell it taxed, sometimes for as much as ten
times the market value, to the merchants. More prudent than his Han predecessors, Yen
opened offices and stores only in the salt producing areas because he felt that '...if the
officials were numerous the people would be oppressed..' although this good intention was
short lived, for as the monopoly grew in power, so did the bureaucracy. For even in
relatively peaceful periods, the provincial governors might have army garrisons of between
20 and 90 thousand men doing non military duties in canal and river transport as well as
local industries. Regulations for Military Colonies assessed the number of workers and
graded production: civil regulations authorised the 'prefectural services' to manage the
salt pools in the north with the instructions to rent them out to families who were
skilled and capable of working them efficiently and appointing officers to inspect,
supervise maintenance and repairs and to tax the salt produced. With salt manufacture,
storage and marketing regulated to some extent, Liu Yen successfully negotiated a working
agreement with the canal and river transport organization. The overhaul included dredging
and maintenance - paid for out of the profits from the salt and iron commission -
employment of professional crews for the boats and guards for the water traffic and
storage bases along the routes. He also arranged sailing schedules for specific runs on
canals or rivers with boats built to suit the local conditions. Bulk cargoes mostly went
by water and here again, the Chinese led the West in marine technology by fitting
bulkheads some 500 years earlier; and their river salt boats had 'preflooding' sections to
cushion the damage from bouncing and crashing when shooting the rapids on the way down
from Sechuan to the Yangtze valley.
THE POPULATION SHIFT
FROM NORTH TO SOUTH
For many centuries, even before the Han Dynasty, there had been a
population movement southwards. Here the land was more productive, the climate more
temperate and a higher standard of life prevailed than in the harsher northern conditions.
Yangchou, at the junction of the Yangtzee River and the Grand Canal was already
established as the centre for the canal network and was ideally positioned for the
amalgamated Salt Administration and the Transport Commission. It also became the economic
center for the whole country. Liu Yen was made a commissioner for public revenues, salt
and iron, taxation and transport in 763 AD. Two years later he and Ch'i were sharing the
financial control of the whole country between them. Ch'i represented the Public Revenue
Department, an important body in the Central Government responsible for the budget which
took over the northern provinces and Szechuan, while Yen, as commissioner of the Salt and
Iron Administration became dominant and powerful in the south. (Map) Financially it was
immensely successful. In less than 20 years the Salt and Iron's contribution to the
national revenue rose from 600,000 strings of cash to between 6 and 7 million strings -
nore than half the annual income. (Table) But the high peak was not sustained. In the 780s
there were serious uprisings in the north east and more money was again needed urgently.
The salt taxes were raised - five fold in some parts of the country - a hardship made
worse by continuing deflation and disorder in the Central Salt monopoly administration.
Reform of the system produced an improvement in the revenue so that by 900 AD salt was the
top item in the budget with the south of the country contributing the entire salt ration
for the army. But during the next hundred years the number of soldiers increased from
200,000 to over a million so naturally the monopoly tax went up - three and a half times -
since it was levied mainly to meet defence expenditure. About 60% of government money was
spent on maintaining the forces. By 1160 the annual budget was 40,000,000 monetary units
and the supporting taxes were salt 50%, wine 36%, and tea 7%.
PAYING THE TAXES
Before the 10th century most taxes in China were paid in kind;
typically, the land owner paid in grain and his wife paid with her woven cloth; or a
number of families might combine to provide a soldier, a horse or some lengths of silk;
the salt areas paid in salt. After 780 the land tax, first imposed in the state of Ch' in
594 BC, was assessed in cash with regional variations. The prosperous Yangtze delta, ahead
of most other provinces responded by paying this and the poll tax in money.
PROSPERITY, POVERTY
AND INVASION
Between 960 and 1279 AD. during the time of the Sung dynasty was a
period of great trade expansion and growth in the economy with the introduction of paper
money and more copper cash in circulation. (see chap on Money) It was a time of high
interest rates - as much as 20% a month - and of poverty, especially among the employees
in the state monopolies; for example, the 280,000 families working under semi feudal
conditions in the Huai salt marshes. Culturally, it was also a distinguished epoch for
town planning, landscape gardening, painting and of course, scientific invention. However,
in spite of having the most technically efficient army in the world, it did not prevent
China from being swept into the Mongol Empire towards the end of the 13th century. The
invaders over ran much of the country with brutal fury but they agreed to a wise
suggestion to 'set up taxation on land and merchants and make profits on wine, salt, iron
and the produce of the mountains and marshes.'
A NEW MONETARY
POLICY
Their successors, the Ming Emperors, found themselves ruling over a
much larger kingdom the any earlier dynasty with 3 million men in the army, many
garrisoned on distant borders and in need of supplies. Merchants willing to transport
grain there received salt certificates as pay in exchange for delivery which entitled them
to trade the government salt at lucrative prices. They were also encouraged to colonize
these outposts by farming the land. But surprisingly, in 1492, when payment was changed
over to money instead of salt the merchants lost interest and stopped. Many were rich
having '..commonly some hundreds of thousands of ounces of silver and the great traders of
Huai-Chou in Kiangsi province might have made up to a million strings of cash through fish
and salt..' so that their influence in government could no longer be ignored. As the key
economic areas became settled and affluent - by the late 13th century 85% of the
population and two thirds of the national wealth were located there - market towns sprang
up along the Grand Canal and the main waterways with storage points and customs services
to support the interegional trade. It was the chief center for mining, the textile and tea
industries: and Szechuan, with its advanced salt technology and minting money skills was
the first to introduce paper money as early as 1024 AD.
IMPLEMENTING THE
MONEY PROGRAMME: A MIXED ECONOMY.
There had also been a population swing away from the overwhelming
proportion of the workforce engaged in agriculture with a fivefold increase in the numbers
of people working in offices and about three times as many merchants as before. More taxes were levied in money
including salt under a mixed economy of paper money and copper cash. '..everyone was
obliged to go to market to sell and buy ... peasants poured into the cities to sell their
products or become traders and artisans..' writes Balacz. There was more freedom to trade
and increased decontrol in industry: the salt tax collection in money rather than the
commodity had taken place around 1500 AD and after 1617 salt was no longer stored in
government depots. The merchants too, along with the continuing evolution of the money
economy had also prospered.
MARKETING THE SALT
Those 'odd, unsettled people ...the traders and merchants, 'with
uncertain means of subsistence were ranked below the gentry, the peasant, the artisan and
craftsman in a rigid social hierarchy based on birth and occupation. They were subject to
personal harassment and traditonally forced to wear distinctive dress such as one white
and one black shoe or to having their name and business displayed on their turban, which
nowadays might be considered a good advertising gimmick but was then a humiliating sign of
social discrimination. Extra transit dues, duties and registration were common penalties.
The 'gentleman merchant' was usually a member of a gentry family having capital or a loan
and typically working in the grain or salt monopoly business; but he could not own land or
enter the civil service examinations except by illegal means and was therefore excluded
from a government career.
After all,the salt and iron monopoly it was declared, had been
introduced to 'crush' the rich merchants so as to prevent hoarding and illicit saltmaking
However, during periods of prosperity and decentralisation in the provinces, the
restrictions were relaxed and merchants could buy themselves into a business or industry.
One such opportunity occurred in 1644 when the Ch'ing authorities appointed 24 wealthy
merchants to manage the transport organization giving them important hereditary rights to
licences and control over the smaller traders which seems to have been unusual and was
perhaps an acknowledgement of the influence and social status achieved by merchants at
this time. The transport organization, much of it already in private hands, could offer
great opportunities for enterprise and profit; and so could the salt monopoly though both
were very vulnerable to abuse.
THE SMUGGLERS
Salt smuggling was always endemic and widespread in China as it has
been elsewhere in the world. The outstanding reasons were, briefly, the rather severe
regulations governing the shipping of cargoes; lack of economic incentives; a larger
volume of trade giving greater opportunities for illicit saltmaking and illegal sales.
Violent plunder increased when both shippers and bandits were armed and influential people
with vested interests in the salt industry failed to demand investigation and reform.
EXPLOITING THE SALT
The salt monopoly was run on a complicated system of quotas, licences
and certificates with different gradings and marketing outlets - inland the tax was higher
than at the coast for example - not to mention tax free weighting, grain tribute ships
carrying salt free of charge and fishing boats which had their own legal allowances. There
were plenty of loopholes to be exploited: and they were. A shipping publication in Ming
times carried warnings about short measure, false returns and corrupt practices for every
type of cargo and 'any number of sly frauds ... such as drilling holes in kegs of oil or
purposely shift(ing) government monopoly salt about looking for an opportunity to steal it
.. so there is no bag which escapes being pilfered ..' Low priced blackmarket contraband
would be sent on its way through the canals by bribing transport officials to allow it on
board and then turning a blind eye on its disposal at the end of the journey. Later in the
19th century, there would be gangs of 'as many as a 100 and several tens of men ...in the
markets ... they load up their salt and openly display it for sale .. at about half the
price of government salt. Or again, the Muslim folk ... along the sea coast in the Hopei
province make a business of selling illegal salt .. 300 to 400 men use donkeys to carry
their salt, calling them 'salt donkeys.'
A BRAVE ATTEMPT AT
MITIGATION
But in 1892, one official, Tao Chou, did have some local success in a
bid to stem this corruption at Liang Huai in the eastern coastal plain north of the
Yangtze river. (Map). Production yards there covered a 1,000 sq. miles and employed about
400,000 workers, most of them with private or semi-private status - a large organization
even by modern standards. In theory the management was shared between the Emperor, the
Board of Revenue and the local authorities. In practice it was the local personnel
together with leading wealthy merchants who were responsible. With official support and
vigorous leadership Chou was successful in reducing salt smuggling on the canal boats and
from the Liang Hui yards by searches and arrests. At least one
bandit fleet ceased operations while he was in charge. He also achieved lower production
costs by 'un-co-opting' some powerful merchants holding hereditary licences and replacing
them with more modest, able and trustworthy men. He stimulated salt sales considerably and
reduced the backlog of unsold quotas. But he was not able to get the price down low enough
nor to stem the flow of illegal salt from over the borders of adjacent provinces. And he
failed to keep pace with his current deliveries, so that his achievements in boosting the
sales and efficient policing must be set against his inability to deliver on time.
CHINA IN THE
TWENTIETH CENTURY
At the turn of the twentieth century the salt trade was still a
monopoly with the country divided into circuits; price differentials varied greatly and
customers were limited to buying from licenced dealers in their own area. Duty and taxes
were levied at the depots and in transit; private saltmaking forbidden and movement of
salt from one circuit to another was regarded as smuggling. In a population which seems to
have been around 400 million, the average adult salt consumption was about 9lbs a year - 3
lbs less than in T'ang times.
Nevertheless, it was a steady, reliable income good enough to be
accepted together with the rapidly increasing customs as security for the foreign loans
needed to 'modernise' China. One of the most important, the Reorganization Loan for #25
million, was raised by Britain, France, Russia, Germany and Japan in 1913 with the proviso
that a number of foreigners should be appointed to co-operate with the Chinese in the Salt
Administration management and to see that the revenues were repaid.
The maritime customs duties on the other hand were predominantly
foreign controlled since they depended on revenue for imports. But both were 'shielded
from warlord interference by the treaty powers involved in their collection ...' Trade was
booming and by 1917 the customs revenue was strong enough to carry the loan repayments
with only nominal participation by the salt administration The trend towards privatization
in 'modern China' had continued, so that by 1950 only one third of the salt industrial
works were state or co-operative owned; the rest were private businesses. Ten years later
the wheel had turned full circle and 98% were in the public sector. And China was the
second largest world producer of salt.
The salt monoply in China was an integral and intimate part of the
organized state from early times. The industry successfully applied advanced technology to
exploit deep drilling, lifting and piped transport from their brine well long before the
Western world. Financially, the monopoly raised significant amounts of revenue for wars,
rebel movements and state enterprises and in doing so created employment but much hardship
for the poorer sections of the population as well as serving the long standing interests
of eminent persons. And it took part in the 'moderniization' of China in the 20th century.
Now, the tax on salt is
used as it should be, to regulate the price between user and producer throughout the
republic.
Research shows salt was lifeline in history
Three Gorges Reservoir
Salt was for a time the
lifeline for social and economic development
in today's Three Gorges' Dam area of the
Yangtze River,China's longest, said
researchers after a recent tour to ancient
salt processing centers in the area.
The researchers, including
archeologists and historians, have collected
enough cultural heritage items and specimens
to explain how salt was processed and
distributed in the region in history.
"Many wars were fought in
the area over the control of salt
resources," said Wang Chuanping, an official
in charge of archeological excavation and
heritage protection in the region.
Salt has always been the
lifeline in China's history, said Prof.Ge
Jianxiong with the Shanghai-based Fudan
University. "Whoever controls salt has the
power to decide his own fate and that of all
others," he said.
The Three Gorges' Dam
area, where brine springs abound, used to be
a center for salt processing and
distribution. Experts have unearthed a huge
amount of chinaware pieces in the region,
which they believe were used for salt
processing and storage.
"The rich salt resources
in the Three Dams also helped the great
ruler Ying Zheng, the first emperor of the
Qin Dynasty (221 -207 BC), to unify six
rival states into one country and establish
a form of government which had a lasting
influence on Chinese feudalism," said Prof.
Ge.
Archeologists have been
racing against time to rescue cultural
relics facing submersion under the Three
Gorges Reservoir, turningthe area into the
world's biggest archeological worksite.
China was
linked with
other parts
of the world
mainly
through two
routes in
ancient
times. One
was the Silk
Road in
northern
China. It
started from Chang'an, or
present
Xi'an City,
and went
westward to
central Asia
through
Xinjiang.
The other
was the Cha
Ma Ancient
Road in
southwest
China. It
transported
tea, grain
and salt on
horse back
all the year
round.
Related Links | Activities | Email List |
PHYSIOLOGY | GEOLOGY | ARCHAEOLOGY | PALAEOCLIMATOLOGY | EUSTATIC SEALEVELS | DEAD SEA LEVELS | PALAEOGEOGRAPHY | PRODUCTION SALTPETER | RELIGION | ECONOMICS | INDIA Monopolies | CHINA Monopolies |
FRANCE the Gabelle | THE MANY USES of Salt | ETYMOLOGY | MONOMANIA
COPYRIGHT NOTICE AND DISCLAIMER ©
Copyright David Bloch, 1996. All rights
reserved. Copying of this document in any material form is prohibited other than as
necessary for the purpose of viewing on this Web site. The contents of this document is
for general information only. Nothing in this document constitutes legal advice. |
This web page and those derived
from this page, gives collected information derived from other sources believed to be
accurate at the time of storage on available Internet disk space.. These web pages are non
commercial, and academic in purpose, and are stored as personnel information for the page
owner's own use. No warranty of accuracy, reliability or completeness is given and (except
in so far as liability under any statute can be excluded) no responsibility arising in any
other way for errors and omissions or in negligence is accepted by the author and page
owner, David Bloch MRBLOCH SALT ARCHIVE, in the event that others access these pages |
|
|